All of Timothy Telleen-Lawton's Comments + Replies

[I have only read Elizabeth’s comment that I’m responding to here (so far); apologies if it would have been less confusing for me to read the entire thread before responding.]

I have always capitalized both EA and Rationality, and have never thought about it before. The first justification for capitalizing R that comes to mind is all the intentionality/intelligence that I perceive was invested into the proto-“AI Safety” community under EY’s (and others’) leadership. Isn’t it fair to describe the “Rationalist/Rationality” community as the branch of AI Safety/X-risk that is downstream of MIRI, LW, the Sequences, 🪄HPMOR, etc?

[I’m coming back to the comments in this post now and feeling grateful for all the engagement with our podcast. Apologies for being very low engagement on LW for the last decade.]

I just (re-?)noticed that I never addressed your curiosity about machine editing.


Yes, we made heavy use of an automatic transcript/audio editing tool. We can get you the name of it if desired, though I recommend reaching out to me offline if I don’t reply here sufficiently quickly to any follow-up questions you or anyone might have.

Your curiosity helps me realize that I think we s... (read more)

Awesome, thank you! I'm not sure if we're going to correct this; it's a pain in the butt to fix, especially in the YouTube version, and Elizabeth (who has been doing all the editing herself) is sick right now.

The group I played with (same as Mark Xu's group from comment above) decided that "S2 counting is illegal (you have to let your gut 'feel' the right amount of time)" and "repeating some elaborate ritual that takes the same amount of time before your card is due is illegal" (e.g. you can stick your hand 10% of the way towards the pile when the number's 10 off from your card, and 50% of the way when it's 5 off.)

Metaphors We Live By by George Lakoff — Totally changed the way I think about language and metaphor and frames when I read it in college. Helped me understand that there are important kinds of knowledge that aren't explicit.

What I get from Duncan’s FB post is (1) an attempt to disentangle his reputation from CFAR’s after he leaves, (2) a prediction that things will change due to his departure, and (3) an expression of frustration that more of his knowledge than necessary will be lost.

  1. It's a totally reasonable choice.
  2. At the time I first saw Duncan’s post I was more worried about big changes to our workshops from losing Duncan than I have observed since then. A year later I think the change is actually less than one would expect from reading Duncan
... (read more)
8Duncan Sabien (Deactivated)
(I expect the answer to 2 will still be the same from your perspective, after reading this comment, but I just wanted to point out that not all influences of a CFAR staff member cash out in things-visible-in-the-workshop; the part of my FB post that you describe as 2 was about strategy and research and internal culture as much as workshop content and execution. I'm sort of sad that multiple answers have had a slant that implies "Duncan only mattered at workshops/Duncan leaving only threatened to negatively impact workshops.")

All of these answers so far (Luke, Adam, Duncan) resonate for me.

I want to make sure I’m hearing you right though, Duncan. Putting aside the ‘yes’ or ‘no’ of the original question, do the scenes/experiences that Luke and Adam describe match what you remember from when you were here?

5Duncan Sabien (Deactivated)
They do. The distinction seems to me to be something like endorsement of a "counting up" strategy/perspective versus endorsement of a "counting down" one, or reasonable disagreement about which parts of the dog food are actually beneficial to eat at what times versus which ones are Goodharting or theater or low payoff or what have you.

Agreed I wouldn’t take the ratanon post too seriously. For another example, I know from living with Dario that his motives do not resemble those ascribed to him in that post.

I don't know Dario well, but I know enough to be able to tell that the anon here doesn't know what they're talking about re Dario.

+1 (I'm the Executive Director of CFAR)

What do you recommend if good data is too costly to collect?

I think that if someone has made a claim but failed to use good data or an empirical model, it should not require good data or an empirical model to convince that person that they were wrong. Great if you have it, but I'm not going to ignore an argument just because it fails to use a model.

0Shmi
Also, regarding believable arguments, consider reading http://squid314.livejournal.com/350090.html
2Shmi
Collect better data anyway, real and simulated. Otherwise someone will wave a different argument and reject yours. Happens here all the time.

I agree with your definitions of the two curves, although I don't know what point you're making by the distinction.

In either case we can ask, "how much will changes in demand affect equilibrium quantity?" In a constant-cost industry, the answer will be 1:1 in the long-run (as indicated by a flat, or infinitely elastic long-run supply curve), but as you gradually shorten the scope over which you're looking at the market, making it a shorter- and shorter-run supply curve, it will steepen (elasticity decrease) such that the answer is "less than 1:1".

-1Furslid
First, is that because they are different things it's not a contradiction to what I said. The second is that elasticity is not validly applied to long term supply curves, as they are not a function of supply in terms of price.

Great! This is the only 'complete' argument I've seen that our prior for animal products industries should be that they are increasing-cost rather than constant-cost. I'm not as confident as you seem to be, but that's more of a quibble at this point, and I'm glad we agree on the meta-prior!

The challenge then is to convince Norwood and Lusk that we want to know the long-run impact of consumer choices on animal production, not the short-run! They're clearly estimating short-run elasticities since (a) their supply curves are way too steep, even for an increas... (read more)

Given our confidence for opposing positions and your credentials my best guess is that there's a miscommunication, in which case my guess on your correctness won't be well defined. Perhaps there's some critical word I'm using colloquially that has an importantly different meaning in economics.

6James_Miller
Yes and it's "supply curve". Consider one point on a a firm's supply curve which let's say represents price=$1 and quantity=1000. This means that in the hypothetical situation in which this firm could sell as many goods as it wanted at a price of $1, it would want to sell 1000 goods. There is no reason why a few customers not wanting to buy the product would change this. True, a few customers not buying the product would change the demand curve, which would change the market price, which would change where on the supply curve you will end up, but it won't change the supply curve. The supply curve only changes when holding price constant (and assuming the firm can sell as much as it wants at this price) the firm wants to sell a different amount. This might seem like a small point, but to correctly use supply and demand analysis you need to distinguish between moving along a supply curve (because price changes) and moving to a different supply curve.

The most important factor of production in haircuts is human labour. If you double the population of a country, then you double the number of haircuts demanded, but you also double the amount of labour supplied.

To get around the objection of increasing labor, let's assume instead that everyone in the country decides to permanently get their hair cut twice as often as before. What do you expect the real price of haircuts to be in 10 years? Significantly higher, about the same, or significantly less? My prior is "about the same" until I have mor... (read more)

Given your credentials, I can't fathom you disagree that shifts in demand can cause shifts in the short-run supply curve in the long-run. E.g. if lots of people start/stop eating meat, the short-run supply curve will look different 5 years from now due to that change alone.

Given that I believe you agree with that, I deduce that you only mean that changes in demand cannot shift the short-run supply curve in the short-run, nor shift the long-run supply curve in the long-run. With that I do agree by definition.

Funny that the only post by someone acknowledging... (read more)

3James_Miller
NO! I'm curious, given my credentials with what probability do you think I'm right? Edit: I'm embarrassed by this, but I retract what I said.

You're the first person who disagrees with my conclusion but is willing to admit that some industries will be decreasing-cost (wherein we should expect greater than 1:1 effect on production); that is very refreshing!

in the extreme, every industry is increasing-cost, simply because of resource scarcity (consider the situation if computer game demand was so high that 90% of the population worked as game developers).

Yes, I agree in the extremely-large case. What about the extremely-small case? It's very hard to think of a fledgling market for which the av... (read more)

39eB1
Without looking at data, my prior on meat production being an increasing cost industry is extremely high. 1. Meat production is a commodity product. Commodity products compete mainly on price, and so we should expect the industry to be fairly normal (i.e. the sort of industry discussed in econ 101 courses) in terms of competition, costs, etc. 2. Meat has a number of costly inputs, including feed, water, land and labor. If you have several commodity inputs, you can expect that at least one of them would be a potential bottleneck to increasing the scale of the industry at constant cost. For example, we know that water usage is definitely increasing cost, because the next efficient option after depleting our reservoirs is desalination which is stupid expensive on agriculture scales (and this flows into feed prices). 3. Meat production is an extremely large and mature industry. We should expect that large and mature industries have scaled up to the point where marginal costs are increasing, because they have had the time and intelligence invested in them to pick the low-hanging and high-hanging productivity fruit. 4. People who eat meat would like to eat more of it, if only it were cheaper. For example, if MacDonalds introduced a third-pounder for the same price as a quarter pounder, most people would buy it. Since this situation exists, it is probably difficult to provide meat at cheaper prices holding other relevant factors stable. One can imagine another industry where people have no particular desire to purchase more of the given product if the price were lower, such as child car seats and so the industry is limited in size before it achieves minimum cost scale. Of course, in some sense this dodges another question, which is what is your prior probability prior to. If you had never heard of economics, and were just talking about abstract categories which industries either were a member of or were not a member of, then perhaps you could presume a 50% meta-pr

The default assumption is that industries are increasing-cost, because low-hanging fruit is picked first.

I agree this effect will push towards an increasing-cost industry, but there are other effects at play that might be even more powerful such that the industry is constant- or decreasing-cost. For an extreme example, consider the market for computer games; I expect this to be a decreasing-cost industry (the more people buy computer games, the cheaper-per-quality they will be in the long-run, even ignoring technology improvements). For a more moderate ... (read more)

0Salemicus
This confuses supply and demand. The most important factor of production in haircuts is human labour. If you double the population of a country, then you double the number of haircuts demanded, but you also double the amount of labour supplied. Similarly, oil prices wouldn't rise if oil demand doubled... but every oil field doubled in size and output rate. You are right that some industries may be decreasing-cost at certain margins, and computer games sound like a plausible candidate due to the low marginal cost. However, in the extreme, every industry is increasing-cost, simply because of resource scarcity (consider the situation if computer game demand was so high that 90% of the population worked as game developers). This is why the default assumption is increasing-cost. Neither of these publications make any suggestion as to whether most industries are increasing or decreasing cost in those articles, as far as I can tell. The fact that they don't make such a suggestion doesn't mean that we shouldn't have a prior.

If just one consumer decided to not buy the good at any price this is what would happen.

Yes, I'm referring to a decrease in a consumer's purchases at any price (such as someone becoming vegetarian in a chicken market) not just at one price (in which case, if the price lowered a cent, they would re-enter the market); I agree this also counts as a decrease in demand.

The answer is that it depends, and the decrease in sales could be tiny or huge depending on elasticities.

Yes, if you mean 'long-run elasticities' then we agree. In fact the only thing that... (read more)

3James_Miller
Sorry to repeat myself but by definition a change in demand by itself can not effect the supply curve, short or long run. If Policonomics says otherwise then it's wrong. I'm an academic economist, the author of this textbook, and the host of this podcast.

Based on the comments to this article I realized a stronger appeal to established economic theory would probably be more convincing. I've made that appeal in a separate post: http://lesswrong.com/r/discussion/lw/lj0/misapplied_economics_and_overwrought_estimates/

OK so you have no prior for large cases, you have no prior about the relationship between large cases and small cases, and your guess for small cases is "zero impact".

My prior for large cases is 1:1 impact, my prior is that the impact in large cases is proportionally similar to the impact in small cases, and therefore my prior for small cases is 1:1 impact.

-1Lumifer
Let's be clear about distinguishing between the map and the territory. To what do your priors apply?

My "not buying a chicken" seems like it would look very similar to anyone else's "not buying a chicken".

Thanks for acknowledging that.

I think standard economics agrees with your vision of "~always positively-sloping finite supply curves" in the short term, but not necessarily the long term. Here's a quote from AmosWEB (OK, never heard of them before, but they had the quote I wanted)

As a perfectly competitive industry reacts to changes in demand, it traces out positive, negative, or horizontal long-run supply curve due to increasing, decreasing, or constant cost.

1Furslid
Long term supply curves are different than supply curves. They are similarly named, but different concepts. Supply curves measure supply at a price. Long term supply curves measure market equilibrium supply as demand changes over time. The elasticity measurement is the derivative of supply with respect to price. It cannot be applied to long term supply curves.

Oops, I meant to edit that rather than retract. Since I don't believe there's a way to un-retract I'll re-paste it here with my correction (Changing "Supply Elasticity is 1" to "Supply Elasticity is finite"):

Cumulative elasticity = Supply Elasticity/(Supply Elasticity - Demand Elasticity). A cumulative elasticity factor of one means a demand elasticity of 0.

I believe your math skipped a step; it seems like you're assuming that Supply Elasticity is finite. I actually claim in the original article that "the 'price elasticity of s... (read more)

1Furslid
I'm sorry, that is correct. You were describing a supply curve that doesn't behave normally. So I can't say anything about demand curves. I apologize for the cheap shot. In the standard economic models, supply and demand curves have elasticity that is a positive, finite number. Infinitely elastic curves are not possible within the standard models. The priors I start with, for any market, are that it behaves in a manner consistent with these economic models. The burden of proof is on any claim that some market is behaving in a different manner.

Cumulative elasticity = Supply Elasticity/(Supply Elasticity - Demand Elasticity). A cumulative elasticity factor of one means a demand elasticity of 0.

I believe your math skipped a step; it seems like you're assuming that Supply Elasticity is 1. I actually claim in the original article that "the 'price elasticity of supply' in the arbitrarily long term becomes arbitrarily high". In other words, as "length of 'term'" goes to infinity, the Supply Elasticity also goes to infinity and the cumulative elasticity factor approaches 1 for a... (read more)

[This comment is no longer endorsed by its author]Reply
2Timothy Telleen-Lawton
Oops, I meant to edit that rather than retract. Since I don't believe there's a way to un-retract I'll re-paste it here with my correction (Changing "Supply Elasticity is 1" to "Supply Elasticity is finite"): I believe your math skipped a step; it seems like you're assuming that Supply Elasticity is finite. I actually claim in the original article that "the 'price elasticity of supply' in the arbitrarily long term becomes arbitrarily high". In other words, as "length of 'term'" goes to infinity, the Supply Elasticity also goes to infinity and the cumulative elasticity factor approaches 1 for any finite Demand Elasticity. Stepping back, I worry from your sarcastic tone and the reactive nature of your suggestions that you assume that I am trying to 'beat you' in a debate, and that by sharing information that helps your argument more than it helps mine, I have made a mistake worthy of mockery. Instead, I am trying to share an insight that I believe is being overlooked by the 'conventional wisdom' of this community and is affecting multiple public recommendations for rational behavior (of cost/benefit magnitude ~2x). If I am wrong, I would like to be shown to be so, and if you are wrong, I hope you also want to be corrected. If instead you're just debating for the sake of victory, then I don't expect you to ever be convinced, and I don't want to waste my effort.

That question seems to have a simple answer: your decision will not affect the long-term production of chicken.

OK, so I argue option A, you state option B, and the articles I link argue option C.

That is a much more complicated question

I agree it's a complicated question (in that it requires lots of information to answer precisely and accurately). If you had no empirical data to work with, what would be your best guess/expectation? Also if your answer is proportionally different than in the 'single chicken' case, I'd be curious to know why.

-1Lumifer
If I had no empirical data, I would not be making any guesses in this case. The "single chicken" case is below the noise floor. Empirically speaking, the consequences are undetectable. And for "many chicken", how many matters -- I don't think there is a straightforward linear case here.

Right. In this case, to answer the question, "If I decide to reduce my lifetime consumption of chicken by one, should I expect the long term production of chicken to drop by ~1, ~0, or something in between?" Which is of demonstrated interest to the authors I am critiquing.

-3Lumifer
That question seems to have a simple answer: your decision will not affect the long-term production of chicken. Now I suspect that the real question is "If X million people decide to stop eating chicken, what would happen to the long-term production?" That is a much more complicated question which I don't think can be answered by moving or bending the supply and demand curves under the ceteris paribus assumption. One reason is that it's scale-dependent: different magnitude of X gives different answers. If X is small, its effect would be swamped by other factors (e.g. the growing prosperity in the developing world which generally leads to more people eating meat) and at the other end, obviously, if everyone stops eating chicken the production would drop to zero and chicken will become extinct.

What you are effectively claiming is that there are no suboptimal producers of chickens. Unless every producer of chickens is ideally located, ideally managed, ideally staffed, and working with ideal capital there are differences in production costs.

It's not that this will ever actually be the case, but the argument is that, in the long term, the market approaches what you would expect with such assumptions (and continues to have short term fluctuations away from that). But yes, even this assumption is clearly not actually true in all cases (as with all... (read more)

-1Furslid
Cumulative elasticity = Supply Elasticity/(Supply Elasticity - Demand Elasticity). A cumulative elasticity factor of one means a demand elasticity of 0. A completely inelastic demand curve is not to be expected in standard economics, and as such it is an inappropriate prior. Thanks for the math demonstrating my point.
0Lumifer
That is an excellent question, but it requires an additional piece: good for what purpose?

Empirical evidence is nice and often more convincing than theory, but I don't think it's necessary for an argument to be convincing (to believe otherwise would be quite... burdensome).

In this case, the original articles I am critiquing used purely theoretical arguments to claim that there will be long term price elasticity of supply, and I think that a theoretical critique is sufficient to show that the strength of their arguments is currently too weak to support the complexity of their theory.

I'm certainly open to any empirical evidence that may exist. Would you find a quick analysis of Big Macs moving (or if not, do you have a suggestion for a different empirical analysis)?

-1Lumifer
The first question is whether you're interested in being convincing or in getting an accurate map. Economics, in particular, is well-known for its fondness for theoretical arguments which tend not to hold up in real life. You'll have to specify what you are looking for. In particular, how long is "long term"? What kind of goods or industries you want to include and exclude? For example, it wouldn't be hard to find both price and supply (=production) data for major commodities (oil, copper, wheat, etc.). You could plot a scatter graph, attempt to fit a model....

No, I haven't looked at the empirical evidence because I didn't think it would be as convincing as the 2 theoretical arguments I made in the original post; let me know if you are aware of any such analysis.

Would you accept the results we find from an analysis of Big Macs as relevant?

  • Since Big Macs aren't generally transported across national boundaries, we can think of the market for Big Macs in each country as largely independent.
  • While we would both expect various factors such as the price of labor to affect the price of Big Macs differently in each co
... (read more)
1Lumifer
Heh. It seems we have pronounced... methodological differences :-D

In the specific example, they could be cloned by expanding in the good locations.

More generally, if you're claiming that there's a limited supply of good locations from which to produce chickens, then that reduces to a "finite inputs" argument I discuss in the last section of the OP. (For further discussion see responses to this comment .)

In short, I agree that such effects can create a sloping long term supply curve in some cases, but I also believe that there are other effects that can lead it to slope the opposite direction, and it's not immed... (read more)

1Furslid
What you are effectively claiming is that there are no suboptimal producers of chickens. Unless every producer of chickens is ideally located, ideally managed, ideally staffed, and working with ideal capital there are differences in production costs. There is a reason, that economics assumes that the amount of a good supplied changes as price changes, and I haven't seen any argument that exempts the case of chickens. Also, how does the market create less chickens as demand falls? If there are differences in cost, the highest cost producers leave the market as price falls. Easy to answer with the standard assumptions, but almost impossible with your nonstandard prior.
4Lumifer
Do you have empirical (as opposed to economics-theoretical) support for this prior?

This is true in the short term, but in the long term, the dynamic changes for producers:

  • The producers that know how to make chickens for $8 scale up or their production strategy is replicated by others.
  • The marginal cost of production (and hence price) keeps falling until all producers are making no profit (relative to opportunity cost of capital)
  • The industry can scale up/down (in the long term) to meet changing demand, but it can't drive prices any lower. If prices were any higher the industry would scale up in the short term and keep expanding until t
... (read more)
1Furslid
No. It's true long term as well. What you have listed are forces that drive the cost of production down. However, they cannot flatten all costs. For example, some locations are better for producing chickens than others. Better weather, cheaper labor market, ease of transportation to slaughter, etc. These factors cannot be cloned. It's only the marginal producers that have costs at or just below the price.

I think your scenario is a good illustration of "finite inputs", which I listed as one of five example ways in which the long term supply curve may not actually be flat (at the end of the original article).

While I think that finite supply is a very real force (that, if strong enough, would create significant long term price elasticity of supply as you claim), the other four examples I mentioned also seem very real to me, and it's not obvious which ones win out for any particular industry.

If Cost always grew with industry size, products in big in... (read more)

So what you are basically saying is that in the long run the price will be driven close to the lowest average price -- right?

Yes; in the long term the producers that have higher-than-average Costs will be driven out of the market.

Still not quite, as once you recognize that "perturbations" will happen, you need to engage in some risk management (zero mean does not imply zero volatility). In your scenario the chicken producer seems to be fine with the 50% chance of going bankrupt at the delivery time which isn't a good assumption to make.

I'm... (read more)

If the received wisdom is that a larger chicken industry will increase the price of chicken feed, then my prior is that it's true in the short term, but not the long term. Chicken feed might be in finite supply, in which case Cost might grow with chicken industry size, but there are other reasons I can imagine Cost might shrink with increasing chicken industry size (listed in original article) and I don't have enough confidence about any of these factors to break my prior that Cost at industry size 2X is ~Cost at industry size X.

Huh? A flat supply curve means that the producers will produce the same number of chicken regardless of the price at which they can sell them. I don't see why this should be true in long term.

I mean "horizontal" rather than "vertical". In that sense, a flat supply curve means a constant price, not a constant quantity.

Not quite. You are implicitly assuming that the Cost is fixed in stone and it isn't. The chicken producer should accept all 10-year forwards on chicken if and only if he can buy matching forwards on his production inpu

... (read more)
-1mwengler
The received wisdom is that if the demand for chicken feed goes up, the cost and price will go up, if the demand goes down, the cost and price will go down.
-1Lumifer
So what you are basically saying is that in the long run the price will be driven close to the lowest average price -- right? Still not quite, as once you recognize that "perturbations" will happen, you need to engage in some risk management (zero mean does not imply zero volatility). In your scenario the chicken producer seems to be fine with the 50% chance of going bankrupt at the delivery time which isn't a good assumption to make.

It's important to note that supply and demand aren't perfectly linear. If you reduce your demand for meat, the suppliers will react by lowering the price of meat a little bit, making it so more people can buy it. Since chickens dominate the meat market, we'll adjust by the supply elasticity of chickens, which is 0.22 and the demand elasticity of chickens, which is -0.52, and calculate the change in supply, which is 0.3. Taking this multiplier, it's more accurate to say you're saving 7.8 land animals a year or more. Though, there are a lot of complex c

... (read more)

One can be very modern and say that supply and demand curves are not real, but they are.

I'm not arguing that supply curves aren't real; I'm arguing that the super-long term supply curve is virtually flat (the price elasticity of supply is arbitrarily high). I find it compelling to imagine a chicken producer accepting contracts to produce chickens 10 years from now. At what prices and quantities would the producer accept the contracts? I would say it would accept all contracts at or above the Cost, at as high a quantity as possible. With lead time and ce... (read more)

-1mwengler
Yes you are. And I think this is wrong. And here is why (stated differently from my original reply which also thought it was wrong). Consider a world in which the entire demand for chickens is one guy who lives on the island of Kauai. In Kauai, chickens run wild through the streets and yards and fields. Since there is this one guy who buys a chicken every week, the shopkeeper scoops up a chicken in his yard on his way to work whenever he knows his chicken customer is coming. Cost of production, close to zero. Consider an alternative world in which everybody is eating a chicken every day. The chicken producers certainly buy up lots of land in low cost places where it is cheap to build chicken production. This doesn't fill the need, i.e. price is way above the marginal cost to produce the last chicken. So they build chicken production closer to centers of demand, where real estate and labor are more expensive. This doesn't meet demand, i.e. price is still higher than the marginal cost to produce the most expensive chicken. Finally, someone builds 10 level chicken coops with HVAC systems, water desalinators to provide drinking water to the chickens, and pays a fortune to process the chicken poop into a benign fertilizer product which they essentially have to give away in order to keep it from stacking up around their chicken coops. Finally demand is met. The point is, demand is filled by suppliers that pay different costs to create the chickens they sell. The cheapest producer makes the most profit, he is lucky. The most expensive producer makes just enough profit to keep producing, the slightest drop in price will put him out of business. Even within a given production facility, the marginal cost to produce an extra chicken rises as the "capacity" of the production facility is filled. So for the christmas rush, 10% more chickens are grown, but it raises the costs of the facility 15% because they are paying night-workers instead of day workers, they are having to b
0Lumifer
Huh? A flat supply curve means that the producers will produce the same number of chicken regardless of the price at which they can sell them. I don't see why this should be true in long term. Not quite. You are implicitly assuming that the Cost is fixed in stone and it isn't. The chicken producer should accept all 10-year forwards on chicken if and only if he can buy matching forwards on his production inputs, otherwise he is exposed to the risk of, say, the price of feed going up.

Yes; another way to think of this is, "How do you model waste?"

  • If you think waste is best modeled by a fixed percentage of all production, then our best guess about the waste is that it changes proportionally with consumption. We don't get to magically assign our consumption to the 'waste' category without highly specific information (such as, "I found it in a dumpster").
  • If you expect the percentage of waste to grow/shrink with industry size, that could be an argument for slightly less/more than 1:1 effect (I'd put it in the "Ga
... (read more)

In your model, how can you tell how close a market is to reaching the thresholds you suggest? In other words, if we are somewhere in the middle of converting a "large swath" of the population to vegetarianism, how can we tell if we're at a point of 1 effect?

My guess is that we can't distinguish between those cases, in which case the best we can do is to average out over all long periods of time/market states and estimate that our long term effect is 1:1 (even though, in every case, it probably isn't exactly that).

-1Epictetus
I mostly brought that up as something to keep in the back of your mind when working with a simplified linear model. You could see bifurcations and nonlinear behavior in real life.

Hi, I've been following LW and the occasional article for a couple years but have never posted any comments. Now I'd like to post an article but I need 20 karma to do so. If you don't mind up-voting this comment to allow me to do that, please do!

If it helps, the post I've drafted is about some of the altruistic eating arguments I've seen in the broader LW network such as:

I use one neoclassical eco... (read more)

1Timothy Telleen-Lawton
Thanks to everyone who granted me karma! I just posted the article here: http://lesswrong.com/lw/lgy/how_much_does_consumption_affect_production/