This question is just for my interest. Suppose you, the US government, have a finite supply of 65k H1B visas that you're prepared to offer per year, and you want them to go to the most economically valuable applicants. You could set a fixed fee, but then you'll run out of visas by the end of the year. You could have a blind auction every few days, but then companies have to wait until an auction happens to be certain of the outcome. It seems like instead, it should be possible to set a dynamic fee, that always offers a company a price to purchase any number of H1Bs (less than the total amount remaining), but that ensures that a number near to the total are offered per year?

To summarise, and abstract away the details of the scenario, I'm looking for a mechanism that works for the case where there is a finite supply of n items that has the following properties:

  1. you always offer a price for any number m items that is less than the total remaining
  2. when a customer makes a purchase, they definitely receive the items
  3. about as much economic value is created, as possible, from the sale
  4. you earn about as much revenue as possible

Presumably there's some intersection of queuing their and mechanism design that is designed to answer such a question?

New Answer
New Comment

4 Answers sorted by

Measure

Feb 19, 2022

80

You could set a fixed fee, but then you'll run out of visas by the end of the year.

It sounds like your fee is too low.

Seriously though, set the price as some function of remaining time and remaining items (example: p = C*d/n, where d is days remaining, n is items remaining, and C is a constant.) If someone wants multiple items, the price is just the sum of the prices for that many items purchased individually.

Or auction off the next year's visas as a big batch auction. Everyone submits their bids over the course of the year, and at midnight 1 January the visa price is set to whatever clears the market. Every visa is allocated at the revenue-maximizing price, you know precisely when you will know and that you will be guaranteed a visa if you win, it is allocated to the most willing-to-pay applicants, etc.

The downside is that it increases latency by as much as a year (if you wake up at 12:01AM on New Years and realize you want to emigrate that year). You can trad... (read more)

2RyanCarey2y
Yeah I think in practice auctioning every day or two would be completely adequate - that's much less than the latency involved in dealing with lawyers and other aspects of the process. So now I'm mostly just curious about whether there's a theory built up for these kinds of problems in the continuous time case.

Nice idea. But if you set C at like 10% of the correct price, then you're going to sell 90% of the visas on the first day for way too cheap, so you can lose almost all of the market surplus.

3Measure2y
My thought was that you'd set C at your best guess clearing price or maybe a bit higher. You could instead go with 10x the clearing price and plan to not sell many before the last month but maybe get a bit more revenue overall.

RyanCarey

Feb 19, 2022

20

My feeble attempts here.

James Payor

Feb 19, 2022

10

Auction off VISAs once a year, price them at the median of the winning bids, and allow the winners to resell them for at most 10% more.

This answer doesn't come with a strong epistemic status on my part, but seems like it has the components needed to work, perhaps with different numbers though.

In this answer we're trying to equitably split gains-from-trade, and not capture every drop we can :) And we don't handle the case without resale.

thefirechair

Feb 19, 2022

00

Sell 180 visas per day over 6 hours between 9am-3pm for 361 days of the year. A new auction every two minutes of one visa. Final day of the year sell remainder of visas and take four days off until new year.

Start Jan 1 and say Google bids $10000 x 10 visas. They win the first ten auctions over the first 20 minutes. The reference price is set at $10,000 for auction #11.

But $10,000 is too high for the next bidder who wants to pay $9000. No sale on auction #11.

Auction #12 starts with 2 visas for sale. You decrease the reference price by 2/180. 

So new min reference price is $9888 and there are two visas for sale. If no sale we move to 3/180 decrease for next round. 

Down to $9724 and three visas for sale. Keep repeating this decrease until the price reaches the next highest bid. 

As prices decrease with each unsold round buyers who are looking for, say, six visas for the year would see prices that are perhaps higher than they'd like but they can get all six visas bought in one lot. 

If a sale occurs of any number then the next round doesn't decrease in price. 

Bidders can bid for any number of visas at any price at any time of the year. There are always 180 new visas up for sale every day. If some big company wants 1000 visas and is willing to pay then the first 1000 auctions go to them at their price point. 

By only decreasing the price by the percentage of unsold, it stops large price drops. You can set a minimum figure it never goes below.

Big businesses might want 200, 500, 1000 visas and be willing to play the auction to see if they can get a good price. So if they log in on day 50 of the year and see 140 visas for sale at $5000 each, they might buy all of them just to guarantee they at least get 140. 

Then two minutes later there is 1 visa for sale at $5000 and the bidding keeps going.

Carryover any unsold and add it to the total. If 30 carry over then the next day has 210 visas for sale. First auction of the say is 30 unsold + 1 new. If no sale the new cost cut is 31/210 x reference price. 

If the first 10 visas went for $10K each and then there was no sale until auction number twenty, you'd see the price drop to $7363 at ten visas for sale. 

If a single business just wants one, they have an opportunity to buy at $7363. Or they can toss their bid in at $5000 and let it simmer to see if the reference price ever drops to $5000. 

~ I have zero idea what these visas go for by the way so plug in whatever figure is closer to reality. If the gov wants $20K min then that's the min price. Jan 1st 9am the auction opens, you'd see the price rise to $32K and sold. Then $33K sold. Then no sale, drop of 2/180 x reference price and so on. 

2 comments, sorted by Click to highlight new comments since: Today at 9:28 PM

Price and auction theory is a big field of study.   I think I'd question why the hard limit of 65K visas in a calendar year - why 0 or 20M (aka, what's the theory of value that makes you issue visas, and is direct revenue part of it, or an afterthought?)

Assuming it's totally out of my control how the visas come into being, and totally in my control of how to distribute them, and I ONLY care about revenue rather than fuzzier economic or social encouragement of the recipients, I'd probably go with a weekly auction, where the quantity available is based on projected pricing.

[-]jmh2y20

Perhaps I'm missing something. Looking at the problem and the properties listed aren't the visas just normal economic goods? In that case maybe a better question to ask first is "Where is the market failure." that prevents the market exchanges from achieving the claimed market results of maximizing total welfare?

I would think the idea, without some failure identified, would be to walk down the demand curve, letting the highest bidder buy as many visas as it wants so that seems like a pretty standard auction process.

I do suspect there is an interaction here between the specific recipient of a visa and the sponsor that would be bidding for have a visa allowing the import of the employee/human capital. I suspect that might be a relatively small distortion point but perhaps should be considered.