A universal basic income (UBI) is often presented as a public insurance against large-scale and potentially permanent technological unemployment. Many Silicon Valley leaders that believe in the transformative economic potential of artificial general intelligence have also voiced their support for UBI (e.g. Sam Altman, Elon Musk).

UBI can be a part of the policy tools to address long-term technological unemployment. However, it is worth highlighting that a UBI to address long-term technological unemployment is more expensive than current UBI proposals and that it is not a sustainable solution to finance an insurance against widespread loss of labor income by taxing labor income:

  • A post-labor UBI is expensive because it would not merely supplement labor income, but fully replace it. Additionally, the more affordable alternative of a guaranteed minimum income would approach the cost of a regular UBI in a post-labor scenario.
  • To explore the challenge of financing a UBI in a scenario of large-scale technological unemployment we will examine the case study of Switzerland. The Swiss were the first worldwide to vote on a nationwide and fairly generous UBI in 2016.

In short, distributing money through a UBI can be a solution to a lack of labor income. However, the hard part is designing income streams that grow in lockstep with the parts of the economy that grow in a scenario of high automation and accordingly can finance a rising demand for UBI or other forms of social security.

1. UBI for technological unemployment is expensive

1.1 A guaranteed minimum income is cheaper than UBI, but would approach the cost of UBI in a post-labor economy

In the public discourse, the terms UBI and guaranteed minimum income are often used interchangeably. However, they denote different concepts and many famous “UBI proposals” and “UBI trials” are actually guaranteed minimum income proposals and trials. The main reason for this is that guaranteed minimum income is much cheaper to implement than a UBI. However, in a scenario of large-scale unemployment the costs of guaranteed minimum income would rise rapidly and approach the cost of a UBI.

Universal basic income

A UBI is commonly defined as having the following characteristics:

  • Periodic: a recurrent payment (e.g., every month)
  • Cash payment: paid in cash, allowing the recipients to convert their benefits into whatever they may like.
  • Universal: paid to all, independent of income, employment status, children, health status or other factors. Not targeted to the poorest or those who need it most.
  • Individual: paid on an individual basis (versus household-based).
  • Unconditional: involves no work requirement

In a UBI everyone actually receives a transfer payment. The idea is that making the payments universal increases buy-in for the program and reduces the stigma of needs-based benefits (“like a school uniform”).

Visualisation of a UBI in a labor economy with income on y-axis, market income in blue, UBI in red.

A good example of a UBI proposal is the “Freedom Dividend”, the signature policy proposal of the 2020 Democratic primary candidate Andrew Yang. The proposal would give every US-citizen over the age of 18 1’000 USD per month per person. 

Guaranteed minimum income

A guaranteed minimum income or negative income tax is the idea that the state will ensure that everyone reaches a minimum monthly or yearly income. If you don’t reach it, the state will pay the difference, otherwise you will not get anything. So, while the cash payments do not require any active action, payments are withdrawn as labor income rises.[1]

Visualisation of a guaranteed minimum income in a labor economy with income on y-axis, market income in blue, and guaranteed minimum income in red.

Good examples of guaranteed minimum income proposals are those put forward in the United States in the 1960s and 1970s by Milton Friedman, Richard Nixon, and George McGovern

In a labor economy, a guaranteed minimum income is a lot cheaper to implement than a universal basic income of the same amount. However, this also means that the costs of a guaranteed minimum income program would rise rapidly in the case of technological mass unemployment as the number of beneficiaries expands. In contrast, the cost of a UBI remains the same regardless of the number of unemployed and underemployed.

Visualisation of how a guaranteed minimum income in a full automation economy might look like with income on y-axis, capital income in blue, and guaranteed minimum income in red.

1.2 A public spending-neutral UBI is not enough in a post-labor economy

Supporters of UBI like to point out that a remarkably heterogeneous coalition of thinkers including technologists, libertarians, and socialists support the idea of a UBI. However, as always, the devil lies in the details.

Thinkers on the left, such as Philippe Van Parijs & Yannick Vanderborght (2017), generally look at a relatively generous UBI as a foundation to build stronger and much more expansive welfare states. In contrast, libertarian thinkers, such as Charles Murray (2006), are more interested in a public spending-neutral UBI. In other words a UBI that is entirely financed by replacing existing welfare spending. 

a) A public spending-neutral UBI would reduce income for some low income households

A spending-neutral UBI reform financed by cutting a large fraction of existing social security programs would increase the amount of beneficiaries that receive a share of social security spending (everyone) at the expense of lower spending per beneficiary. Meaning, it would generate more winners than losers among the population. However, the average loser loses more than the average winners gains. In most countries the current allocation of social assistance programs is more effective in reducing poverty than a spending-neutral UBI reform.[2]

Under spending-neutrality the UBI would have to be set considerably below national poverty lines. According to the OECD, a budget-neutral UBI would amount to €158 per month per adult in Italy, £230 in the United Kingdom, €456 in France, and €527 in Finland.

b) A UBI large enough to maintain or increase transfers to all low-income households would be very expensive 

Financing a UBI at 100 per cent of the national poverty line for adults and 50 per cent to children up to 15 years old, would cost between 20 and 30 per cent of GDP in middle income and high income countries and 50 per cent or more in low income countries (graph below). 

Source: Isabel Ortiz et al. (2018). Universal Basic Income proposals in light of ILO standards: Key issues and global costing. ilo.org p. 15

c) In a post-labor economy we would optimally have a universal high income

A universal basic income should be enough to live on, but just barely. The exact amount differs based on regional income and purchasing power levels. However, most proposals are set below and at best at the local poverty line. The idea is that you have peace of mind if you need to leave an abusive partner, a toxic job, look after a child or try to pursue self-employment. However, you should still be incentivized to seek employment again.

In contrast, if the premise is a persistent problem of technological employment that renders a significant share of the population “unemployable” then a basic income is not exactly utopia. It would ensure that no one starves but it would essentially create a permanent underclass. Hence, some, such as Elon Musk, hope that a growing machine economy will enable a “universal high income”, where humans can comfortably live indefinitely without having to work.

Today, most “UBI” trials use some mechanism to select participants with low income and are closer to a guaranteed minimum income. They are tested as an alternative to other forms of social security or as a supplemental income to low-income households. Hence, they may find that people receiving a UBI have improved well-being. Who wants to run the experiment measuring the well-being effects of replacing the salary of programmers with a 1’000 USD a month UBI?

2. Financing a UBI by taxing labor is not “post-labor proof”

Let’s look at the Swiss popular initiative “For an unconditional basic income”. The initiators have proposed[3] that all permanent resident adults should receive 2’500 CHF (ca. 2950 USD) per month and all children and young people 625 CHF (ca. 730 USD) per month. These numbers were also used in an accompanying volume of essays published by supporters of the initiative and the government has used these numbers as the basis for official calculations presented in the official voting material. 

Specifically, the government calculated that the proposed universal basic income would cost about 208 billion CHF annually (ca. 30% of GDP) to cover 6.5 million adults and around 1.5 million children and young people.[4] In discussions with the initiators, the government calculated that the basic income would replace many existing social security benefits, the corresponding savings could finance around 55 billion. Still, social security spending would have to be nearly quadrupled and an additional 153 billion would be required. Around 128 billion CHF of this could be covered by deducting 2’500 CHF from every earned income, or the entire income for incomes below 2’500 CHF.[5] The remaining gap of 25 billion CHF or so would have to be financed by significant savings or tax increases. For example, the VAT could be doubled from 8 to 16 per cent. 

So, what’s the issue?

2.1 We don’t know how soon we may run out jobs

A further expansion of the welfare state without significant automation may be premature. Many advanced economies face rapidly ageing societies with worsening dependency ratios and historically high levels of public debt.

We also know that there have been previous waves of automation anxiety that ultimately turned out to be false alarms. Supporters of the initiative held a “robots for UBI” protest and stressed the progress of automation: “Robots are doing more and more work. It is now our task to shape society in such a way that everyone has a dignified life thanks to the digital revolution: More meaningful and self-determined activities are possible.”[6] And yet, here we are another 7 years later: We still haven’t even managed to automate trains and many Western economies have labor and skills shortages. Given this context, we may want to scale a UBI incrementally, in lockstep with the expansion of the AI economy.

2.2 Most financing of the Swiss UBI would fall away in a post-labor scenario

Let’s make an extremized thought experiment and assume that AI will replace all human jobs within the next 10 years. Nearly two-thirds of the foreseen funding for the UBI came from labor income tax. If labor becomes obsolete there is suddenly a 128 billion CHF funding gap. On top of that, labor income taxes also form the backbone of the general government budget of Switzerland and most other developed nations. Across the member states of the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), about 50% of all tax revenues in 2023 came from individual income taxes and social security contributions.

In short, as the Genevan law professor Xavier Oberson argued: “Should mass workplaces for humans disappear in the future, from a tax perspective a double negative effect could occur. On the one hand, significant tax and social security revenues would be lost, while on the other hand, the need would increase for additional state revenue to support the growing number of unemployed human workers.” 

Solutions

What is needed to address both the timing uncertainty and the long-term financing issue of UBI with regards to the prospect of technological unemployment is a financing mechanism that scales with the growth of the machine economy. I will explore the strengths and weaknesses of some of the more popular suggestions to address this in future posts.

  1. ^

    This can be based on monthly or annual income checks and with corresponding phaseout provisions. In the extreme case, this can mean that participants have up to 100% marginal tax rate for earning additional income through labor until they reach the minimum income. However, something like 50% phase-out is more common. As Scott Santens has explained, a 100% marginal tax rate reduces willingness to work and hence this is not the best design in the current system.

  2. ^

    Ugo Gentilini, Margaret Grosh, Jamele Rigolini, & Ruslan Yemtsov. (2020). Universal Basic Income: A Guide to Navigating Concepts, Evidence, and Practices. worldbank.org p. 133

  3. ^

    Strictly speaking the text on which the Swiss voted did not specify how high the UBI would be, how it would be financed and who exactly exactly would be entitled to it. In some sense, one can view this as strategic ambiguity to get buy-in from more socialist and more libertarian UBI supporters. 

  4. ^
  5. ^

    This financing mechanism means that even though the Swiss proposal is a UBI in which everyone receives an actual transfer, it would have had the characteristics of a guaranteed minimum income with a 100% marginal tax rate on labor income from 0 to 2’500 CHF.

  6. ^
New Comment
3 comments, sorted by Click to highlight new comments since:

Okay, yes.

And, this is a lot of definitions and details.

Your conclusion,

What is needed to address both the timing uncertainty and the long-term financing issue of UBI with regards to the prospect of technological unemployment is a financing mechanism that scales with the growth of the machine economy. I will explore the strengths and weaknesses of some of the more popular suggestions to address this in future posts.

Seems like the starting point for anyone who's thought seriously about exponential growth in AI labor. It's certainly my starting point, and so I'd hoped that a post with this title would address this issue.

I'm guessing this didn't get more upvotes because it sort of over-promised and under-delivered. 

If you read until the end you will see why this was the right choice - at least based on the argument that it’s an insurance against technological unemployment.

I don't want to read until the end to find out if you have any good ideas to deal with what is (to me, and an unknown fraction of LW readers) the obvious question. 

I was warned to not write scientific articles that are "mystery stories". If you have something worthwhile to say, put it in the abstract; then again in a little more detail in the introduction; then again in more depth in the body of the article.

Don't string the audience along or expect them to read a whole piece on a vague promise. Even if it's mostly payed off, they won't appreciate the mystery story- unless you're a Nobel prize winner and they're excited to read anything you write, in which case, a mystery story can be great.

I upvoted just because I think anyone doing this type of thinking and writing about post-AGI economic solutions should be encouraged. I'm writing this to say why this high-effort piece didn't get more upvotes. I do hope you'll put as much effort into your next piece.

I look forward to your next piece, in which you offer actual ideas for the problem at hand!

 

Most of the people I've read and heard talking about UBI really mean something like minimum income or negative income tax. So talking about the distinction is details and terminology. Most people with half a thought on the matter don't really intend to pay the rich as much as the poor during the transition period when some people still have jobs or income. 

The big question is: how can we tax AI based income enough to pay enough in minimum income to roughly make up for the vast amount of lost jobs once AI labor starts really taking off on the exponential? We should expect large unemployment rapidly scaling toward majority unemployment, happening rather soon one after the other. Check out progress in humanoid robotics, and fit an exponential curve to it along with the one we've fitted to AI progress. Physical jobs will be lost close behind white-collar jobs. 

Soon after, almost all jobs will be gone. The transition period is the important thing to get right.

I assume that's what you're addressing in the next post. If so, and you have either solutions or useful framings of the problem, I expect it to receive much more attention and upvotes.

Thanks for the feedback - appreciated! 

  1. I agree. I'm sort of on a learning curve on how to write for online audiences. Specifically switching from exploratory research to a short narrative style and this probably should have been a much shorter post. (in my defense I have cut a lot, incl. overview tables of all prominent UBI proposals, UBI trials, and some of the main discussion points around UBI impacts).
  2. The fact that financing UBI by taxing labor is not future-proof may be too obvious for LW - I am not sure it has arrived everywhere - some prominent UBI advocates still suggest it as the default funding mechanism.
  3. Yes, I am writing a whole series on the AGI economy, so in some sense this is just the prelude to explain why saying "money is the solution to people not having money" doesn't solve the challenge of getting the money. Texts on everything from robot tax, to sovereign wealth funds, to windfall clause, to OECD/G20 tax treaty, to pension funds, to global commons management will follow

I agree with 2. that UBI not being future proof is not obvious everywhere, and not even to everyone on LW. For a different audience (professional economists?) I think this careful setup would be worthwhile.

I look forward to seeing your proposed solutions! Thanks for taking the feedback in the helpful spirit in which it was intended.