This post was rejected for the following reason(s):
Looks like you’re crossposting this from your blog elsewhere. That can be fine, but sometimes we we’ll reject these crossposts (or allow them but with a warning) if they seem like they’re not quite aimed at the LessWrong audience or adopting LessWrong norms. LessWrong has particular norms aimed at getting towards truth (e.g. avoiding rhetoric, being precise, being quantitative, etc), and your post isn't obviously displaying those. Good solutions to this are to (a) write an extra intro to your post to explain why people on LessWrong might find it interesting, (b) rewrite to be a style more aimed at truth than persuasiveness or engagingness.
The ninja occupy a unique place in Japanese history and popular culture. Typically depicted as master assassins and spies clad in black garb, the real ninja emerged under highly specific historical circumstances in medieval Japan. Their rise and fall is closely tied to the Sengoku period (1467-1603) - an era characterized by intense civil warfare, political turmoil, and uncertainty.
Far from the image of ninja as shadowy assassins, they were predominately spies and mercenaries utilized by warring factions during the Sengoku era. The ninja trace their origins to the Iga and Koka regions, mountainous areas that attracted refugees fleeing violence in the lowlands. Life in the remote highlands necessitated unique survival skills. Combined with influence from warrior monks and an influx of deserters from various conflicts, these regions gave rise to the specialized skills and knowledge that came to be known as ninjutsu.
As central authority broke down in the late 15th century, Japan descended into nationwide civil war. The constant conflict generated huge demand for intelligence and mercenary services. With their specialized skills honed in the unforgiving highland environment, the ninja were perfectly placed to capitalize on the turmoil. As Bottomley and Hopson (1988) note, for marginalized groups like the ninja, "periods of unrest offered unusual opportunities for profit and advancement" (p. 17).
Rather than establish formal governance, the ninja organized themselves into confederations governed by constitution-like agreements. Despite lacking a central authority, they leveraged lucrative mercenary contracts across feudal Japan to attain a higher economic equilibrium typically associated with centralized states.
This seemingly paradoxical outcome was enabled by Japan's unique institutional environment at the time. The prevalence of self-governing leagues known as ikki provided an existing framework the ninja could easily modify at minimal cost to suit their purposes. In this manner, they sidestepped the typically assumed tradeoff between complex economic organization and anarchy.
The ninja confederations successfully balanced security and cooperation for almost a century through private governance. However, their very success ultimately contributed to their demise, as the regions came to be seen as overly autonomous and resistant to centralized control. In 1581, the warlord Oda Nobunaga led a massive invasion force that finally conquered Iga and Koka, ending the era of the ninja confederations.